´´ The J-System (Part Two) - Keiretsu

Tuesday, November 11, 2014

The J-System (Part Two) - Keiretsu

Introduction


Japan's economic performance after WW II till 1990 was exceptional. Japan managed to rise from a country decimated by a world war to one of the wealthiest nations on earth in only four decades.

Especially the high-growth era between 1950 and 1973 flabbergasted many Japan observers. Neither the two oil shocks of the 1970's nor the orchestrated Yen revaluation of the mid 1980's, where the Yen appreciated significantly, put any breaks on the relentless rise of Japan. Quite contrarily, it appeared to had made Japan even more powerful. At the latest when corporate Japan began trophy shopping in the U.S, and started to hoard U.S. icons like the Rockefeller Centre and Universal studios, the sentiment towards corporate Japan started to shift, especially in the U.S. Had it been envied before was it now feared.

Many observers were convinced that the unique governance system of Japan, the J- System, with its three pillars of main banks, Keiretsu and lifetime employment, was the main reason behind corporate Japan's success and seemingly unstoppable ascent.

During that time many pundits marketed the J- System as the endpoint of an efficient corporate governance system. Far superior to the Anglo-Saxon model of shareholder primacy and market disciplin. Even the Economist, usually not known for a socialist agenda, suggested that Japan's intercorporate shareholding structure appeared to have done a better job than most Western economies of filling the "vacuum at the heart of capitalism" that resulted from the fragmentation of ownership accompanying the rise of the modern corporation. Many others also claimed that the traditional public corporations, with large numbers of dispersed shareholders, had outlived its usefulness. They advised the West that it should take the J- System as its model. They advocated the replacement of open stock markets with large-block investments by financial institutions that serve as both equity and debt holders in highly leveraged firms. (Gerlach)

How time has changed! Since the bubble has popped the J- System has come at the center of criticism by foreign observers. Especially by the advocates of the Anglo-Saxon model of corporate governance, which is now marketed vigorously as the endpoint of an efficient corporate governance system. The J- System, on the other hand, has been regarded as a significant structural barrier for newcomers in the Japanese market and a hindrance to the powers of "animal spirit" and Schumpeter’s' "constructive destruction". Broadly speaking the J- System now is held responsible for Japan's inefficient capital markets, inefficient corporate governance and suboptimal economic performance. This perception has significantly heightened by the unsuccessful attempts of overseas investors, such as Steel Partners and T. Boone Pickens, to gain a significant voice in the internal affairs of corporate Japan through the same mechanisms of stock acquisition and takeovers that they have used in the United States.

A lot has been written lately about how outdated the J- System has become. But little is known what really constitutes the J- System of corporate governance and control in Japan. This serious of posts intends to change that and shed some light on the J- System.

In the first part the main bank system was presented.

This second part will be dedicated to presenting and scrutinizing the Japanese Keiretsu network system.

Personal Remarks

I am well aware that this serious of posts does raise important questions regarding the optimal organization of exchange in an economy, i.e. is stakeholder primacy (J- System) or shareholder primacy (Anglo- Saxon System) the most appropriate framework of corporate governance to ensure overall economic efficiency. But those topics will not be dealt with as it would go beyond the scope of this serious of posts. 

Zaibatsu 


The Zaibatsu system was the predecessor of the Keiretsu system. Many of their origins date back to the Tokugawa regime (1603-1868). For example Misui was a political merchant that, among other things, provided financial services to the Tokugawa regime. Others, like Mitsubishi and Yasuda, where founded during and after the Mejii Restauration (1877-1890). At the beginning the "Mejii" Zaibatsu were less diversified than the "Tokugawa" Zaibatsu. But with increasing government protection, subsidies, loans, privatization, etc. they subsequently had grown and diversified in patterns broadly similar to the older Zaibatsu. (Grabowiecki)

Japan had been late and thus on its own path of industrialization and technological innovation. It had been forced to learn new production methods from the west rapidly and to invest in new processes with which it was unfamiliar. Japanese industrial organization had been characterized by rapid rates of change in market conditions and technological capabilities, as well as a permanent evolution in government policies and industrial structure.

The Zaibatsu arrangements emerged within this context. It represented a compromise between the simultaneous needs to retain control over scarce resources and to exploit expanding economic opportunities. Not only did Zaibatsu expand through the kind of elaborate internal hierarchies that dominated business development and where adapted from the United States, but also through subdivisions into quasi-independent units. The Zaibatsu diversified far more completely than their corporate counterparts in the United States. (Gerlach)

Concerning the organizational structure and governance of the Zaibatsu system, guaranteeing family control over the entire Zaibatsu network of (in its day-to-day operations) increasingly decentralized subsidiaries has to be seen as its essential feature. A holding company (Honsha) was at the very top of this network of suppliers, subsidiaries and dependent firms, wielding control over those firms. Issuing stocks by the Zaibatsu subsidiaries allowed to expand into new business ventures and created an increasing pyramidal Zaibatsu structure of member firms over time. It allowed to raise a tremendous amount of private capital, while the founding family retained complete control over the holding company and its subsidiaries (network firms) (Grabowiecki)

An additional important source of control by the honsha over its subsidiaries in the prewar Zaibatsu was through directors sent out to the subsidiary firms. For example, by 1945 the Mitsui holding company held twenty-one directorships in its subsidiaries, Sumitomo fifty-one, and Mitsubishi eighty-five, or an average of about two to four directors per first-line subsidiary (Gerlach).

The process of forming new subsidiaries and subsequent share offerings of the network firms to the public was repeated till the family ran out of promising investment opportunities. (Grabowiecki)

Zaibatsu
(Zaibatsu)

 


-1-

Pages: 1 2 3 4 5 6

No comments:

Post a Comment